Ha Joon Chang: Confused on Bounded Rationality and Economic Regulation

In this third and final of the series on Ha Joon Chang’s critique of ‘free market economics’ I examine his account of ‘bounded rationality’ and the case for greater economic regulation. As in much of his work the policy conclusions which Chang draws simply do not follow from his premises.

In chapters 16 and 19 of 23 Three Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism, Chang asserts that free market economics rests on the view that actors are fully rational and that individuals always know what is in their best interests when deciding to buy, sell and invest. Drawing on Herbert Simon he argues that people often do not know what they are doing because the limitations of the human brain make the world too complex to fully understand. Thus, there are often advantages from restricting individual choice in order to reduce the complexity of the problems people face. One way to do this is to rely on administrative hierarchies such as firms, which operate on internal command and control procedures. The existence of corporate firms which ‘plan’ their activities Chang says demonstrates that so called ‘free market economies’ are to a significant extent ‘planned’ – and that the existence of such hierarchies demonstrates that ‘planning’ is often superior to more decentralised structures. Similarly, rules and regulations that limit choice can result in better decisions. Just as consumers who have limited attention spans often adopt routinised decisions – such as buying well known brands rather than risk unknown products – so rules and regulations can reduce the complexity of the choices people face and limit the things that may go wrong. From this Chang concludes that we should see greater government regulation not as an inhibitor of economic growth but as a way of reducing uncertainty. In the specific context of financial markets he argues that to avoid future crises complex financial instruments should be banned ‘unless we fully understand their workings and their effects on the rest of the financial sector and … on the rest of the economy’ (p.177).

Reading Chang’s book you would never know that free market economists such as Coase , Hayek and Vernon Smith have done more than anyone to examine bounded rationality and the role of hierarchy and rules as social ordering mechanisms. Granted, 23 Things is a semi-popular work not a purely academic analysis – but an honest attempt to convey what ‘free market economics’ is about would have made some reference to these writers contribution – assuming Chang understands it.

Hierarchy and rules have a role to play in any economy – but under bounded rationality there is uncertainty about what types and levels of hierarchy and which rules are desirable. Chang seems oblivious to the role that market competition plays in determining how much hierarchy, and what rules we should have. Having cited the extent of organisational hierarchy witnessed in firms he states that, ‘The question is not whether to plan or not. It is what the appropriate levels and forms of planning are for different activities,’ (p:209). True – but these words could have come straight from the mouth of Ronald Coase – a free market economist who won a Nobel Prize for work on the theory of the firm. In his Nobel address Coase notes:

“To have an efficient economic system it is necessary not only to have markets but also areas of planning within organisations of the appropriate size. What this mix should be we find as a result of competition,” (716).*

Unlike Chang, Coase recognises that the type of planning that goes on in markets is categorically different to governmental planning because – unless particular organisations are granted regulatory privileges by the state (of the sort Chang favours) – it is arrived at via voluntary cooperation. Freedom of contract enables people to enter into a range of competing institutional structures and to discover through a process of evolutionary learning which are best suited to different tasks. Big firms, small firms, owner-managed firms, joint stock companies, partnerships, mutuals and cooperatives all compete for workers, sales and investment capital. By contrast, government planning is imposed on all by the force of law. People cannot – save for leaving their particular country- exit from government plans. The scope for organisational learning is thus diminished and the risks of failure should fallible politicians and planners make mistakes, are correspondingly more far-reaching.

A similar argument applies in the case of social rules. Hayek and Vernon Smith argue that people rely on rules in order to overcome the limitations posed by their ignorance. But unlike Chang, they emphasise that these rules should, wherever possible, be voluntarily subscribed to and subject to competition from potentially better adapted alternatives. Voluntary conventions and private codes of conduct are typically enforced through reputation and ostracism rather than direct coercion. Those who wish to challenge a rule can ‘break’ the relevant convention without needing legal approval –and if successful they may provide role models that can be imitated. The role of government, therefore, should be limited to providing the basic protections, such as security of property and contract law, which give the maximum scope for people to experiment with their own private rules of conduct. The greater the extent of centrally imposed regulation the less scope there will be for decentralised evolution, the more difficult it will be to remove maladapted rules, and the greater the danger of a ‘systemic failure’ should the wrong rules be chosen.

Contra Chang the major lesson of the financial crisis is not the need for more regulation- but for greater competition between different forms of regulation in order to reduce the risks arising from the bounded rationality of regulators. As Jeffrey Friedman has shown in some detail the problems that afflicted the financial sector arose in large part from the inability of policy-makers to comprehend the combined effects of the maze of interconnecting regulations which have accumulated over the last fifty years. Regulators are as subject to bounded rationality as anyone else but with their unique powers of coercion and immunity from competition they have the capacity to do enormously more harm. From the decision of monopoly central banks to keep interest rates at excessively low levels; to the regulatory inducement of government-backed mortgage companies to relax lending requirements for low income families; to internationally enforced capital regulations which induced banks to securitize risky mortgages; the creation of legally protected monopolies in the credit rating business which prevented alternative ratings methodologies from arising; and the creation of deposit insurance and implicit bail out guarantees which have reduced incentives to avoid excessive risk, coercive government rules have induced all manner of disastrous unintended consequences.

With his proposals to ban complex financial products Chang seems unable to recognise that given appropriate background incentives boundedly rational actors in markets (whether individuals or institutions) can adopt an easy ‘rule of thumb’ when faced with decision-making complexity – ‘if you don’t understand it, then don’t buy it’. This is not an option they face when dealing with centrally imposed regulations and mandates. If the financial crisis has taught us anything it is that the public needs protection from regulators and central bankers who don’t understand what they are doing. If we are to reduce the risk of future crises then we should limit the scope for governments to impose new rules and regulations unless they can demonstrate what these consequences will be.

* Coase, R.H. (1992) The Institutional Structure of Production, American Economic Review, 82 (4): 713-719.

** Friedman, J. (2009) A Crisis of Politics not of Economics: Complexity, Ignorance and Policy Failure, Critical Review, 21 (2-3): 127-183.

This article has now been re-published in the collection ‘What Caused the Financial Crisis’ (2011): University of Pennsylvania Press.

9 thoughts on “Ha Joon Chang: Confused on Bounded Rationality and Economic Regulation

  1. Thanks, Mark, for this series. Outstanding. I’m living in South Korea where Chang is considered to be a national hero. Not surprising, considering his followers 1) aren’t asked to take responsibility for anything 2) aren’t asked to do anything 3) are given many scapegoats to hate, especially voluntary exchange 4) he has plans–big plans, huge international restructuring plans. People have taken over countries with that kind of formula; thankfully Chang is just selling books and hasn’t gone into politics to directly force his vision on others.

    I have had your first blog post translated into Korean, we’ll knock out parts 2 and 3 next and post links to them here. The president and CEO of CFE has also written some articles in Korean about Chang, we will translating those soon and also posting them. http://eng.cfe.org/mboard/bbsDetail.asp?cid=mn1309270313&idx=2017

  2. Casey,
    Many thanks for this – glad you like them. This is the last for now, but I’m sure I will return to him given the frequency of his public pronouncements the latest of which was a bizarre article in The Guardian published this week.
    Thanks again for your support
    Mark

  3. Mark, would I be wrong in thinking that the concept of bounded rationality applies even more to a central economic planner than to an entrepreneur, because a central economic planner has countless variables and unknowns to consider as part of the greater economy, while the entrepreneur needs only know the specific variables and unknowns of his target market? It is this premise alone that first drew me to a free-market/libertarian/decentralisation point of view.

    To me, the arrogance of Chang citing bounded rationality as a reason for central planning is reason enough to be sceptical of his work – that he should rate his (or a central planner’s) intellect so much higher than others’ is just frightening.

    1. Completely misses the point again. The mention of bounded rationality is to show that free markets do not necessarily lead to optimal outcomes. The argument as to how government intervention (Chang specifically opposes Central Planning, the fact so many commentators keep confusing this issue shows how superficially and carelessly Chang has been read by critics) can overcome bounded rationality problems is based on the way a coercive mechanism can overcome collective action problems (all this is explained in Political Economy of Industrial Policy where he deals with the issue of informational asymmetries in great detail).

      I worry about the tone of these blog posts, “Chang does not mention the argument of author A therefore he doesn´t know about or doesn´t understand author A” is highly inappropriate given that Chang is an expert in this field and his written extensively on the people in question (in books and articles that no commenter on these blog posts, nor Mark himself, has actually read yet).

  4. Sorry John, I have read three out of four of Chang’s books – the only one I haven’t is the book on Industrial Policy you keep referring to (which I will read in due course) and nothing I have said misrepresents what is in the 3 books i have read. This post is absolutely on the point that Chang makes in 23 Things.I do not claim that he supports central planning – I do claim that he advocates many centrally imposed rules supposedly as a way of dealing with bounded rationality, especially in financial markets. The post points out that choosing the right set of rules is itself a bounded rationality problem – what if regulators choose the wrong rules? Along with so many other people, you assume that the only way to deal with collective action problems and information assymetries is to rely on coercion – but this isn’t so. There are all manner of private regulatory institutions ranging from firms to stock exchanges which can perform this function – and because they do so in non-coercive context the risks associated with their making mistakes are reduced. It is a bit rich to complain about my not mentioning one of Chang’s books when in 23 Things there is no reference whatsoever to contributions from any ‘free market economists’ on precisely the points he is discussing – e.g. no reference to Coase on Theory of the Firm. I repeat, even in a popular book some mention, however passing, should have been made to this contribution. According to your reasoning though the book isn’t really about ‘free market economics’ , but about the ‘Republican Right’. In that case he should have titled the book 23 Things Republican’s Don’t Tell You About Capitalism’.

    1. Um, Chang hasn´t written 4 books, if you check his website (http://www.hajoonchang.net/books_written.php) it becomes clear that he has written 4 books for the “general reader”. I don´t think you can complain that he doesn´t make reference to Coase in these books since they are intended for a different audience.
      All the other books, and not just Political Economy of Industrial Policy, but also Globalisation, Economic Development and the Role of the State (amongst many others) make plenty of references to Hayek, to Coase and to the arguments you cite. I think to critique Chang on any reasonable academic basis you should at least read these two books (there are many more academic texts he´s written but I think at a minimum these two are a reasonable basis for fair comment since they deal with the issues you bring up).
      The confusion between what Chang advocates and “central planning” (as evinced by the comments made by people reading your blog, see above) come from a lack of careful reading on the part of many people, which sadly your posts are indulging. The language of “if Chang understands or has heard of” is highly inappropriate and worsens this.
      As for non coercive regulatory institutions, well they have “free rider” and “principle agent” problems that are discussed by Chang (better to leave this discussion to your future posts, when you read the texts). You´ll find that Chang actually agrees with the idea that one experiments between different mixes between state level and firm level planning in order to see which mix works out (this is not just Coase, it´s there in Hayek too, in the Constitution of Liberty in his chapter on the importance of freedom of movement as a basis for controlling governments). Chang´s point is that there are different nations, different polities, across the world, and they should be free to experiment rather than having IMF “one size fits all” policies imposed. The natural process of experimentation has shown that Communism is pretty disastrous, and so is Neoliberalism. The countries that have done best, like South Korea and Japan, have been middle of the road interventionists. But again, better to read the materials and then criticise rather than doing so without information.

      1. South Korea and Japan have been doing great since the mid-90s. If only Hong Kong had followed their path instead of their doomed “neoliberalism.”

  5. 私も引っ越しをした時に運転免許の居住地を変更しました。取り替えしないと、置き換えの手続きが会長にできません。

    地域の引越し業者は、低価格で細かな要望でも応えてくれるところが多いです。
    近距離の引越しの時は、大手の引越し業者に比べ、地域の引越し業者の方が良い場合もあります。

Leave a reply to John Cancel reply